Demands for ‘fair trade’ and ‘level playing fields’
as preconditions for free trade used to traditionally target
practices like foreign subsidies and predatory dumping, but
have now multiplied to encompass a range of domestic
policies and institutions, including labour and
environmental standards and technology policy. Social
clauses or international labour standards are being
vigorously pushed forward for inclusion in the WTO by the US
and the European Union, particularly France, and are equally
energetically being opposed by developing countries whose
low labour standards and conditions are under question.
While the social clause debate remains an outstanding ‘new
issue’ with long-term implications for the global trading
regime, it may be mentioned at the outset that it is new
only insofar as being invoked by the developed north since
the 1980s with the visible threat of protectionist barriers
if not accepted by the south.1 As an issue related to
international competition and trade, the social clause cause
has a rich history dating back to the early 19th century,2
pursued haltingly by the US in the pre-Tokyo GATT rounds.
What makes it topical and ‘new’ is the prospect of
labour standards becoming a formal instrument of trade
policy through incorporation in the rules-based WTO.
The original ‘values-based’ impetus for introduction
of universally applicable labour standards and improving
worldwide conditions of work comes from the ILO. It has been
at the helm of an eight- decade old campaign for
international standards to cope with the problem of labour
conditions involving “injustice, hardship and
privation”.3 Through a plethora of non-binding
conventions, recommendations and supervisory mechanisms, the
ILO has attempted to transform working practices in every
country, and claims “thousands of documented cases of
improvement in situations”.4 However, in light of the
absence of compelling enforcement machinery, ILO
achievements need to be judged as modest. Many pro-WTO
social clause advocates in the industrialised world invoke
ILO’s moral terminology and its none-too-spectacular
enforcement by arguing respectively that labour standards
that are ‘low’ are unacceptable, unfair and illegitimate
and that the stick of trade sanctions would work marvels
towards ensuring compliance by errant third world countries.
A question is whether the north has hijacked ILO principles
and embedded liberalism to the trade discourse for selfish
protectionist purposes5 or if OECD countries are genuinely
motivated by solidarity with foreign workers and are lending
the ILO a helping hand. As shall be demonstrated, the former
is primarily the case.
The moral argument in favour of a social clause runs into
rough weather due to the monopoly that the west enjoys in
deciding what is a fair and legitimate standard. This
Chomsky-patented ‘assumption of universality’ and
enforced conformity by the north offends anti-social clause
parties as reeking of Orientalism and imposition. While ILO
bifurcates labour standards into ‘Fundamental
Conventions’ and ‘Priority Conventions’, the American
concept of ‘core standards’ or ‘minimum
internationally recognised standards’ suggests a
compulsoriness and fixity that rewards similarity and treats
diversity (derived from different cultural values, economic
conditions and analytical beliefs) as deviation and hence
punishable offence. It has been pointed out by anti-social
clause thinkers that while the north may enjoy advanced
standards in some areas like basic wages, employment
benefits, minimum working hours and protection of women and
children, its record in areas such as unionisation of labour,
right to strike, worker participation in decision-making on
the factory floor and treatment of immigrant workers is
dismal.6 If it were a pure slanging match over which labour
market is more humane, or which standards are adequately
‘core’ for inclusion in the WTO, east and west
disagreement, except regarding egregious practices like
slave and prison labour (already prohibited under GATT XX),
promises to be prolonged. As long as symmetry of obligations
does not exist in the proposed social clause, the moral
argument will remain one-sided and opposition to it
undiminished.
Economic Impetus
The most significant economic impetus for a WTO social
clause has been the phenomenon of deteriorating OECD labour
markets in recent years and the belief that free trade with
a third world resorting to ‘social dumping’ is the main
causative. In the US, a consistent downward trend began from
the early 1980s manifested by falling real wages of
unskilled workers,7growing income inequalities and
increasing numbers of working poor. Simultaneously in
Europe, high rates of unemployment8 have added to the
popular perception of ‘labour pauperisation’ due to
globalisation of trade and investment. The economics of
‘fair trade’ draws on the factor price equalisation (FPE)
and Stolper-Samuelson theorems which postulate an adverse
impact of free trade on the factor of production that is
scarce in the importing country (by inference, unskilled
labour in the north) vis-a-vis that which is abundant
in the exporting country (unskilled labour in the south),
ultimately leading to convergence of factor rewards. An
oft-cited survey fashioning this linkage argued that
burgeoning trade deficits in the 1980s as “the US economy
became more connected with the rest of the world” led to a
relative augmentation of unskilled labour supply and thus
depressed its real wage.9 Another fear related to the
ill-effects of globalisation concerns ‘outsourcing’,
‘delocalisation’ or relocation by MNEs to low-wage and
low labour standard countries in the developing world,
epitomised by Ross Perot’s demonisation of NAFTA a Pied
Piper’s “giant sucking sound of jobs” as they moved
southwards.10 By implication, unskilled labour-intensive
import competing sectors in the developed world require
protection from developing country cheap imports through a
social clause in the WTO that would furnish disincentives to
social dumping and redeployment of capital by raising third
world wages and creating ‘less exploitative’ work
environments.
Opponents of social clause find no plausible economic
rationale in the trade-induced lower wages analysis and
point instead to domestic distortions in OECD labour
markets. FPE and Stolper-Samuelson thrive on extraordinarily
demanding assumptions (constant technology and tastes) that
are impractical in dynamic real world terms. Technology
diffusion, specialisation, increased competition,
‘X-efficiency’ and economies of scale are among the most
crucial externalities of free trade that generate a
‘lifting all boats’ effect and help converge factor
rewards not negatively (US to Mexico or Europe to China) but
positively by increasing real wages of unskilled labour in
both north and south.11 Borjas-Freeman-Katz fail to
juxtapose the impact of free trade on goods prices with that
on factor prices and are ipso facto unable to prove fall in
real wages (i e, labour purchasing power) owing to US BOT
deficit. According to most leading economists, OECD labour
market travails are attributable to trade-independent
phenomena such as domestic technical and organisational
change. Krugman refers to ‘technology’s revenge’ on
unskilled labour-force by increasing the premium paid to
highly skilled workers in the US as the principal culprit.12
Bhagwati also talks of skill-biased technological changes
unrelated to trade within developed countries that have
resulted in rising wage differentials.13 Robert Lawrence
adds that organisational preferences in manufacturing, in
deference to production techniques, have shifted toward use
of educated white-collar workers and away from less-educated
blue-collar workers. Outsourcing through increased FDI is
another red herring because there is evidence of declining
unskilled labour employment and increased skill premiums
even in multinational affiliates in developing countries,
suggesting reasons other than cheap labour for relocation.14
The corrective to skill and education-biased change is
for affected labour to acquire skills through government
subsidised retraining or lump sum income transfers rather
than demand a social clause and other standard
harmonisations in world trade. In spite of trade
protection or labour standards, domestic technological
trends would continue to affect unskilled labour.
Social clauses concerning child labour, a major area for
setting international labour standards, may also not redress
labour market anomalies or even protect American
import-competing sectors as the 1993 Harkin’s Bill
intended.15 The link between child abusing sweatshops and
cheap exports is not as straightforward as assumed by many
in the west. Bangladeshi textiles, Indian carpets and
diamonds and Pakistani sports equipment are indeed
export-intensive sectors that employ child labour on a
whopping scale, but it is an undeniable fact that the bulk
of south Asian child labour16 comes from rural areas (i e,
farm-based ‘light’ agricultural labour) which is geared
to production for domestic consumption and not export. Even
among industrial sectors employing child labour, Kaushik
Basu estimates that barely 20 per cent of Indian child
labour-ridden firms produce for exporting. If the classic
case of match industry in southern India17 is considered,
even though it is hazardous factory labour employing almost
entirely children, matches or fireworks do not figure in
India’s export list. It may thus be “better to ban child
labour on an economywide scale rather than specifically in
export-intensive sectors”18 not just because the latter
leads to reallocation of child labour into more hazardous
occupations (a la Bangladesh after Harkin) but also as the
harm that Harkin and social clause supporters imagine being
done to northern labour19 is specious and limited to narrow
sectional import-competing interests. A worldwide clause on
child labour “will never have a protective effect” if
the exports originate from labour surplus economies.20
While there are no convincing economic arguments in
favour of a social clause in the WTO.21 it is nonetheless
true that “the issue will not go away” because of the
popularity of wages-jobs-trade linkage among important
domestic constituencies like organised labour and working
population in OECD member states.22 A social clause is seen
as political desideratum by policy-makers in Europe and
America to construct broad consensual support for
multilateral trade liberalisation among labour unions and
the productive workforce. The practical political contention
that labour standards are essential for ‘saving the free
trade system’, i e, preventing traditional tariff barriers
(and the voices to impose them) from rising thus remains. It
is also a case in point that the increased frequency of VERs
as instruments of protection could be curtailed if a social
clause is incorporated into the WTO, thus effecting
important positive effects from an international resource
allocation point of view and reducing the uncertainty in
world economy that discriminatory quotas pose. Mitigating
the effects of unilateral/regional tariff impositions and
VERs and preventing a negation of GATT efforts since 1947 to
eliminate protection could be motives for the south to agree
on ‘core standards’. Since the US position toward
standards harmonisation is all-important at the WTO and the
likelihood of a social clause being mooted by Washington at
the next multilateral round is strong, developing and middle
income countries could judiciously agree at the outset and
retain control over limiting its scope rather than risk a
substantial loss of comparative advantage at a later stage.
The analogy of Intellectual Property Rights during the
Uruguay Round conveys that a determined OECD push for
inclusion of an issue will succeed despite sworn opposition
in the third world. India, Brazil and China could therefore
eschew the dilemma on whether to concede a social clause and
coordinate a proposal on what to include in an inexorable
eventuality.
Political Incentives
Political incentives for a WTO social clause are often
counterbalanced by political hurdles against them in the
south. Standards are seen by sympathisers of developing
countries as cloaks for naked protectionism and denial of
diversity and natural comparative advantage that accrues to
the labour-abundant third world. Integrating new issues into
the WTO might open the door for G-7 interference in
non-trade issues and dictation of the south’s domestic
policies. A pre-emptive agreement on core standards could
end up a slippery slope for developing nations. The
supranational character of a social clause and the
consequent usurpation of national sovereignty over labour
legislation is a very sensitive concern, especially among
former colonised countries living in constant fear of
‘economic imperialism’. Serious doubts have also been
expressed about the purpose of ‘saving’ the free trade
system through a social clause. There are apprehensions of
WTO becoming overburdened and inefficient if it deviates
from its raison d’etre, trade facilitation, by taking on
extraneous issues such as labour standards. “Loading one
specialised agency (WTO) with matters that fall within the
purview of another (ILO)” may result in institutional
competition and capture of free trade by obstreperous
‘labour aristocracies’.23 Prognoses that a WTO Social
Clause would undermine not only the ILO but also trigger a
major north-south split are worrisome reflections that
emerge from these objections.
In conclusion, some modi vivendi between the seemingly
polarised positions on a WTO social clause are worth
considering. Richard Freeman tenders a market-induced social
clause, whereby “genuine consumer demand for labour
standards” (as for environmental standards in the
‘Tuna-Dolphin’ and ‘Beef Hormone’ cases) will shrink
the market of sweatshop products and automatically harmonise
working conditions provided there is accurate information of
production processes through certified labelling.24 Legal
social clauses riddled with ‘psychological
externalities’ and controversy can thus be altogether
avoided to the satisfaction of both north and south. In the
event of a legal social clause being actually enacted at the
WTO, OECD countries could persuade the obdurate south that
standards will improve the exporter’s terms of trade by
making their products costlier ex post.25 Trade adjustment
assistance in the form of development aid, income transfers
and liberalised immigration rules can also blunt the edge of
stubborn southern resistance to the social clause.
Compensatory market access in certain sectors where
developed country tariff peaks are inordinately high could
be brought into the bargain. Last but not least, OECD
economic diplomacy can assuage third world presentiments of
‘managed trade’ and open-ended social clause through
promises not to ‘drift’ into other domestic standards.
These actions might serve as ingredients of the price that
Bhagwati prescribes the west should ‘pay for virtue’.26
Notes
1 US legislation since the
mid-1980s directly linked preferential trade and investment
benefits to respect for basic worker rights. ‘Section
301’ and ‘Special 301’ threatened countermeasures
against denial of ‘internationally recognised worker
rights’. More recently, ‘core labour standards’ are
being used as criteria for granting trade preferences to
developing countries under the GSP. The EC (now EU) adopted
a Social Charter in 1989 and regularly castigates and takes
action against non-conformers.
2 Robert Owen of England, Frenchman Daniel
Legrand, Belgian Edouard Ducpetiaux, and both the First and
Second Communist Internationals showed keen awareness of the
relation between international labour rules and commerce and
advocated reforms to improve labour markets during the
second Industrial Revolution. G Hansson Social Clauses and
International Trade (Kent 1983), pp 12-18.
3 ILO Website, http://www.ilo.org/public/english/standards/norm/whatare/index.htm
4 Ibid. http://www.ilo.org/public/english/standards/norm/enforced/index.htm
5 In Jagdish Bhagwati’s words, whether “the
‘white man’s burden’ is being exploited to secure the
‘white man’s gain’”, Writings on International
Economics (New Delhi 1997), p 501.
6 Anti-union discrimination is marked in a number
of developed countries, including the UK and the US
according to ILO’s Report of the Committee of Experts,
1994.
7 Worker earnings by Consumer Price Index (1979
=100) fell from 95.2 (1980) to 88.8 (1994). Cf R Z Lawrence,
Single World, Divided Nations? International Trade and
OECD
Labour Markets, (Paris 1996), p 20. 8 Almost all
European economies have experienced high levels of
unemployment since 1973 (11 per cent in the 1990s),
particularly among younger, temporarily laid-off and
unskilled production workers. The last mentioned have
suffered a “universal decline in demand”, OECD
Employment Outlook (Paris 1994).
9 The assumption being that “imports have the
potential of displacing production workers more than
non-production workers”. Cf G J Borjas, R B Freeman and L
F Katz, On the Labour Market Effects of Immigration and
Trade (Cambridge 1991) p 4.
10 In Europe, where unemployment is a greater worry
than in America, free trade and delocalisation are being
blamed for labour market ills. See for instance, P Buigues
et al (eds), European Policies on Competition, Trade and
Industry: Conflict and Complementarities (Aldershot
1995), or J Goldsmith The Trap (London 1994). 11 The
rate of increase would of course be greater in the south
than in the north, Bhagwati op cit, pp 512-18. 12 Pop
Internationalism, (MIT 1996) pp 192-203. 13 There is
however, a theoretical trade-dependent technological change
possibility that could reduce unskilled labour’s rewards.
Comparative advantage has become ‘kaleidoscopic’ and
volatile in the last two decades, causing high labour
turnover, which in turn may result in frictional
unemployment and hugely mobile labour gathering zero skills
and consequently receiving lowered wages. Bhagwati op cit,
pp 527-37. 14 Lawrence op cit, pp 102-103. According to
the OECD’s latest survey, FDI chases locations with
‘highly skilled workers and modern infrastructure’ like
China’s ‘Smart’ Export Processing Zones, Cf International
Trade and Core Labour Standards (Paris 2000), p 13.
15 Harkin’s Child Labour Deterrence Act was a direct
response to American labour and consumer organisations
threatening boycott of Bangladeshi garment exports in early
1993. 16 South Asia ranks first in total volume of
children aged between five and 14 years engaged in
production processes, i e, more than one-third of the
world’s working children. It ranks second only to
sub-Saharan Africa in terms of ‘participation rates’ of
children. 17 India has the third highest
‘participation rate’ of children in production after
Ethiopia and Brazil. 18 K Basu ‘Child Labour: Cause,
Consequence, and Cure, with Remarks on International Labour
Standards’, World Bank Paper, December 1998, p 70.
19 An early version of Harkin’s Bill appealed,
“adult workers in the US and other developed countries
should not have their jobs imperilled by imports produced by
child labour in developing countries”, Ibid, p 20. 20 Hansson
op cit, p 175. 21 Extraordinary exceptions are
allowable – (1) Monopolistic exporters using labour
standards as an optimal tariff to shift the terms of trade;
(2) Closely integrated economies like in the expanding EU
where low labour standards in the east threaten mass
migrations and refugee flows into western Europe; (3) The
standard-invoking country or organisation funding the
adjustment cost in the exporting country, akin to the
European Social Charter’s ‘Cohesion Fund’. 22 S
Woolcock, The Trade and Labour Standards Debate:
Overburdening or Defending the Multilateral System?,
(London 1995) p 1-8. 23 T N Srinivasan ‘International
Labour Standards Once Again!’ in International Labour
Standards and Global Economic Integration: Proceedings of a
Symposium, (Washington 1994) pp 35-37. 24 ‘A
Hard-Headed Look at Labour Standards’, ibid, p 27. 25 The
corollary is almost certain deterioration in terms of trade
and overall loss of economic welfare in the importing
country due to the Social Clause, Cf Brown-Deardorff-Stern
‘International Labour Standards and Trade: A Theoretical
Analysis’ in J Bhagwati and R E Hudec (eds), Fair Trade
and Harmonisation: Prerequisites for Free Trade? Vol 1,
(MIT 1996), p 240. 26 Writings on International
Economics, p 504.