BOOK
REVIEW
The
hare and the tortoise
Economic Reforms and Performance. China
and India in Comparative Perspective,
by Subramanian Swamy
Reviewed by Chanakya Sen
The
China-India comparison is a macroeconomist's
paradise, but hardly anyone has managed to
study it at a holistic level of analysis,
economy-against-economy. Harvard scholar
Subramanian Swamy's new book discards the
piecemeal sector-against-sector approach and
manages to create the most comprehensive tale
of the tape between the world's two fastest
growing economies that, ceteris paribus,
are expected to become the world's second and
third largest economies by 2020. Swamy's
central thesis is "conditional Beta
convergence" (if two economies have
different savings rates and technologies,
growth and per capita incomes will converge
conditional on each economy's own steady
state). The Chinese hare may have been the
first to get off the marks and be a quicker
sprinter but the Indian tortoise will
eventually catch up.
Swamy discounts the cliche that the two
postcolonial economies were identical at the
dawn of independence. By 1950, when both
nations were liberated from imperialist
domination, the initial economic conditions
prevailing were varied. China had achieved a
growth rate in foodgrain production (0.6
percent per annum) six times that of India's,
and a marginally higher growth rate in non-foodgrain
crops. Higher per capita grain output and the
absence of many famines in pre-independence
China translated into higher calorific
consumption vis-a-vis India. China's
relatively comfortable food surplus enabled
the country to carry out a strategy of rapid
industrial development, whereas India was
forced to slow down its industrialization due
to two-century-long declines in agricultural
yields.
Before vetting comparative growth rates in the
reform period, Swamy lodges a caveat about the
danger of accepting official Chinese data at
face value. While there is no evidence of
systematic or deliberately fabricated
book-keeping at the National Bureau of
Statistics in Beijing, "Official
mendacity is improbable" (p 28), and
unreliability, uneven quality, dilution (shuifen)
and inaccuracy of figures are serious
problems. Local officials falsified figures
for promotions and to curry favor with
provincial bosses. They tend to overstate
growth of output and underreport investment
and population figures. Annual additions to
inventories are counted as incremental output
and true industrial output is not properly
deflated by a representative price index. A
substantial part of constant price growth
domestic product is in fact calculated in
current prices.
Swamy's facts corrected for
"under-deflation" and
"institutional effect" convey that
Chinese gross domestic product (GDP) growth
since 1980 cannot be 10.1 percent but must be
7.4 percent, compared to India's 6.0 percent.
China's growth rate for 1992-99 is no more
than 6.5 percent. The China-India GDP gap is
thus "not as wide as estimated in World
Bank and UNDP publications" (p 50). It
narrowed considerably in the early '90s and
convergence is well established for the late
'90s.
Today, Chinese life expectancy is longer and
fertility rates are declining, even as the
public sector is being privatized. These
prognosticate a decline in the country's high
savings rate, which in the last two decades
has fuelled China's rapid growth. With
well-designed economic reforms, there is a
strong possibility that the Indian savings
rate will rise to reach the concomitantly
declining Chinese level. If financing costs
are compared, provided the current rates of
inflation are factored in, the real interest
rates for China and India are not that wide
either.
The 2002 Global Competitiveness Report rates
India equally with China in technology and
administrative procedures and evenly matches
the settings for increasing productivity in
both countries. Total Factor Productivity (TFP)
has been declining in China, originally in
agriculture and then for the economy as a
whole since 1992, while it is increasing
slowly in India. It is probable that there
will be convergence in TFP growths in the
coming 20 years.
On the distributive side, China has turned
into a "polarized inegalitarian
economy". Any standard inequality index
places it above India. During the reform
period, both poverty and inequality decreased
in India, but for China, inequality has
increased. Huge interior-coastal disparities
in wealth have led to the coinage of a new
term for regional inequality-induced reduction
in productivity - "Sinosclerosis".
Urban-rural income disparities explain 75
percent of the increase in overall Chinese
income inequalities. They stand at a ratio of
3.5 to India's 1.6. China's Lorenz Curve is
now more convex and outward than India's. In
2002, then premier Zhu Rongji called the
shrinking incomes of rural citizens his
"big headache". There are obvious
economic disadvantages to the government's
plans to reapportion resources to neglected
areas. China's World Trade Organization (WTO)
entry could accelerate this disparity as
coastal provinces and urban areas will benefit
from the expansion of foreign trade, while
agricultural provinces could lose out from
steeper price declines.
How China and India modernize their
decision-making apparatus with information
technology will be a determinant of their
economic destiny in the age of globalization.
Chinese telecom density is more than 20
percent compared to India's 3.5 percent, but
recent deregulation of the sector in India has
raised hopes of a sharp acceleration of this
figure and the possibility of bridging the gap
with China. India beats China by a big margin
in software exports, but Indian software
companies have failed so far to enlist Indian
industries as customers, putting a cap on
growth through the internal industrial market.
China's telecom infrastructure and research
and development (R&D) leads can help
jump-start a spurt in software to match India
soon.
In external openness, the Indian economy is
far behind China's. "Countries that open
their doors to fresh ideas and new concepts
will be the ones that prosper." (p 123)
Still, China's incredible success in trade is
overstated by the "production
chaining" and "double counting"
effects (processing and assembly tasks are
outsourced to the mainland). Its true export
penetration of G3 markets has been exaggerated
for the last decade. Content-wise, China's
much hyped electronics sector trade profile is
a confirmation of its general low-wage labor
intensive status and its inability to climb to
the higher end of the value chain. Unnoticed
by many, China's domestic trade deficit is
shooting up as import liberalization gets into
gear, resulting in an overall current account
deficit in the coming decade. India is
"more securely placed because its foreign
trade is not yet structured on the elements of
processing trade" (p 136). Still, the
subsisting anti-export bias of the Indian
economy is a drag.
Uncorrected Chinese foreign direct investment
(FDI) is 13 times India's, but if
"round-tripping capital" (funds sent
out of China and returned via Taiwan, Macao
and Hong Kong) is excluded and India adopts
the International Monetary Fund (IMF)
definition of FDI, the gap is narrower than
popularly perceived. "The real difference
is not 1:13 but 1:2.5" (p 153). This is
not to deny that India's underperformance in
returns on investment and risk have
discouraged global FDI inflows. In March 2000,
the Indian government inaugurated Special
Economic Zones (SEZs) to attract foreign
investors along the lines of China's
celebrated SEZs. But unlike Chinese SEZs, the
Indian newcomers are smaller in land area,
lack hire-and-fire leeway, enjoy scant access
to the domestic market and have
over-centralized approval systems.
In the wake of the 1997 East Asian meltdown,
Swamy reckons that on a scale of crisis
probability, China's vulnerability has
slightly increased while India's has
diminished. China's greater dependence on
export markets for economic growth is one
reason. The other major cause is that the
Chinese banking system, compared to India's,
is facing severe financial strain and the
threat of bankruptcy. Exposed to innumerable
"soft budget constraints", the
banking sector is a "ticking time bomb
embedded in the Chinese economy" (p.196).
It creates hurdles for private Chinese firms,
especially smaller ones, trying to obtain
capital. Chinese bank lending is tailored to
state-owned enterprises even though directed
credit often ends up as a non-performing
asset.
India's financial system also has acute
maladies. Banks are rewarded more for holding
government securities than for lending. Caught
in a liquidity trap, an Indian bank is left
with barely 39 percent of its deposit base for
commercial lending. Nevertheless, the Indian
banking supervisory system is superior to
China's. India's non-performing loans are
weighty but represent "manageable
systemic risk" as opposed to China's
unmanageable risk. China's fiscal deficit is
in the order of 6-7 percent of GDP (ie higher
than India's). Without urgent financial
reforms, Chinese public debt could exceede 90
percent of GDP by 2010. The political rub lies
in the fact that banking reforms would weaken
Chinese state and party control of the
economic system.
Accession to the WTO requires China to allow
foreign companies freer access to its domestic
market. This has the potential to disrupt
inter-sectoral balances created by the
state-directed economic apparatus and
eventually to sizeably reduce China's growth.
Another warning signal is mass open
unemployment (14 percent) that has remains
after 20 years of reforms and eight percent
growth, spelling socio-political danger to the
entire artifice that Deng Xiao Ping has built.
For India too, Swamy warns of the consequences
of worsening fiscal indicators since the
mid-'90s. Public expenditure has shifted
toward consumption and non-infrastructure
investments since 1995, thereby crowding out
private investment. Labor market reforms are
long overdue not only to attract FDI and cut
wage bills, but also to induct workers with
more contemporary skills and higher
productivity. Unless Indian GDP grows closer
to 10 percent, the country could face
unemployment as high as 16 percent by 2010. A
10 percent decadal growth will, on the other
hand, transform India and pull it abreast of
China. As a minimum condition for closing the
China gap, India will have to make strenuous
fiscal efforts to raise the rate of investment
to 30 percent. Misguided Indian trade policies
that have forfeited millions of jobs,
opportunities and productivity gains to China,
need a facelift.
The Indian economy has lost one precious
decade to China due to delays in initiating
real market reforms. Yet diminishing returns
to capital and limits to exponential growth
give the former a chance to redeem itself in
relation to the Chinese miracle. The 21st
century, Swamy suggests, can belong to both
the Chinese hare and the Indian tortoise.
Economic Reforms and Performance. China and
India in Comparative Perspective, by
Subramanian Swamy. Konark Publishers, New
Delhi, 2003. ISBN: 81-220-0656-6 Price:
US$11.50, 308 pages.
(Copyright 2003 Asia Times Online Ltd. All
rights reserved. Please contact [email protected]
for information on our sales and syndication
policies.)
|